A. Corporate Voting and the Collective Action Problem
Public Corporations and the Voting system
When and how do shareholders vote
AGM
Special meetings – convene as prescribed by law/ written consent if permitted in co./ board called
What do shareholders vote on
Election of directors
Things board cannot do on its own: merger, dissolution, changes to certificate of incorporation, action plan
Cleansing acts: sometimes things that board cannot do on its own
In public co. - say on pay, a non-binding vote on executive compensation
Resolutions under rule 14A(a)
How many votes
One share on vote in general
Required votes for passage
General rule: mergers and charter amendment – majority of shares entitled to vote
Everything else (other than election of directors) majority of shares voting
Election of directors: people with most votes get elected (but now most large co. requires majority of the votes)
Record dates, record holders – how are votes collected
Proxy info given to shareholders Votes collected
Some co. have lawyers that is in charge of the mechanics of vote, complaining purposes, lopsided 90% would vote one way, hard task would be to get enough people to be bothered to vote
Complaints
Shareholders resolution 14A(a) – low level of complaining who gets to insert statement into the co. proxy statement
Intents complaint
Background
Record holders:
Previously shareholders himself would be the record holder (if certificate is lost can get another one)
Nowadays if you buy shares through banks no longer registered as the shareholder investment banks would act as intermediate record holders and passes voting instructions from the company to the owner
Record date – voting date vote still counts even if you sell the shares on the day you voted you vote will still count
Collective Action problem: cost of meaningful collective action paradigm/ model example
Unlike co. wholly owned by a single shareholder (no costs of collective action)
Co. held by 100,000 shareholders collective action costs are likely to be preclusive rational shareholders will never challenge board decisions/ inform themselves about co.’s performance beyond following the price of its stock Voting system largely a formality
Too many shareholders, who would pay no attention to what’s going on
So severe that it makes voting almost meaningless
Board likely to be dominated by top corporate officers (the insider directors), who control the board’s agenda and info
Cost of acquiring info
Benefits depend on
Likelihood that info will change one’s own vote
Likelihood that change in one’s own vote will change outcome (vote pivotal)
Change in value of stock if outcome is changed (= change in co. value x stake)
Example 1
Assume a co. with value of $10B asked to vote on deal that may lower value by 5% (i.e. 500M)
You are suspicious and think chances of this happening are 40%. If you decide to become ‘informed’, you will know for sure
You own 0.1% of the stock (10M value) a lot of money, few would own so many in a co.
You think that likelihood that your vote is outcome determinative is 0.2%
Benefit of becoming informed
Likelihood deal is bad: 40%
Expected loss to company from bad deal: $500M x 40% = $200M
Your portion of expected loss: $200M x 0.1% = $200,000
But you only benefit from casting informed vote if vote is pivotal.
So expected benefit: $200,000 x 0.2% = 400 pretty low for $10 stake
$400 (~30 mins legal advice) most shareholders would not bother to vote
Example 2
Assume co. that you own 3% other shareholders have raised questions about the deal, that you believe vote will be close and the likelihood that your vote is outcome determinative is 7%
Benefit of becoming informed is now: 200M x 3% x 7% = 420,000
Less severe if less diverse; more severe if more diverse
S. 14(a) of the Securities Exchange Act (SEC) was designed to introduce more ‘democracy’ by promulgating a set of proxy rules to encourage informed shareholders to be able to vote knowledgeably in corporate elections
As most do not attend shareholder meeting in person to cast their votes, but give proxies
Proxy = authorization to vote on their behalf for a certain candidate/ proposal
vote authorisation to other people – to vote my share in a following way in the next AGM
co. distribute proxy statements – disclosure statement relating to the vote, recommendation on how to vote
seeking return of a proxy marked voting the way you want them to vote
before AGM, vote is mostly settled
How has the paradigm changed? [11/1]
Reasons:
Ownership structure changed
People have observe that shareholders do not vote in accordance to their paradigm
Corporate election are less one-sided
Changes relating to voting: considered more important now (than 30 years ago)
Increased concentration of ownership
companies are often held by large shareholders less severe collective action problem
Increased institutionalization of voting:
large banks, mutual fund companies (usually own 2-9% in a co.), own a lot of stocks in many companies
With economies of scope, a company can be helpful to another company
Professionally managed, with a lot of advisers
ISS would issue voting recommendations to institutional investors
Proxy advisors
Shareholders’ precatory resolutions more likely to get implemented
Not all management proposals would get majority, sometimes it fails
Hedge fund: unregulated mutual fund, smaller, only very rich people buy shares in them
Some are smaller and have more specialised investment strategies
Active hedge fund: figuring what co. will benefit from the input that would increase in stock price – some are friendly and some are not
“Just say no” campaigns: shareholders vote against management
Voting is taken more seriously - ,ore contested issues:
Shareholders often win
Low no. of no votes will embarrass the board motivate them to do things differently
Board react to how shareholders vote their votes would move the board
Voting is regulated by State law (how to vote) and federal law (solicitation)
Development of shareholders vote
1980s new shareholder’s right movement allowing investors to exercise their power through voting system; SEC amended proxy rules in 1992 to further lower the organising costs of large investors
No longer have collective action costs that are either non-existing (co. only have controlling shareholders) or preclusive (stock held by thousands of small stockholders)
For typical public corporation today, collective action costs may be large, but not large enough to prevent shareholders from monitoring managerial performance, depending on legal constraints, payoffs to shareholders, large culture of shareholder activism structure of the proxy rules and state regulation of voting rights matters the most to these co.
Voting standard in most director election
Plurality voting: nominees with the most votes are elected as director, but need not be majority
Uncontested election:
Previously: if no. of nominees is equal to the no. of vacant seats, a nominee could be elected by a single shareholder (even if all other shareholders refused to vote for that nominee)
Since 2006: companies shifted to majority voting, sometimes implemented via a by-law or a corporate governance guideline
Either case: nominee who receives an uncontested election more “against (or withhold)” votes than “for” votes is either not elected or is supposed to offer her resignation
Where no. of nominees exceeds no. of vacant seat plurality regime
Voting in Corporate Law – Frank Easterbrook & Daniel Fischel
Corporate form allows division of labor between people who have money but not managerial skills and those who have managerial skills but not capital
Legal rules serve as a standard form contract for issues of corporate structures – but structural rules and fiduciary principle together cover only the outline of the relationship and right to voting (including right to delegate such right) is needed to make all decisions that are not provided by the contract (e.g. electing directors and give them discretionary powers over things voters otherwise could control)
Delaware permits firms to give shareholders any no. of votes (including none), and give votes to bondholders in addition to (or instead of) shareholders
Firm may choose to cumulate votes: allowing shareholders to cast multiple votes
[thus a candidate may be elected by less than a majority of the shares]
Those with power to vote may
choose to vote in person or by proxy,
choose mangers directly or through mediation of the board, and
permit directors/ managers to serve full terms or oust them for any or no reason in mid-term
Necessary quorum may be set at less than half of the votes, and the firm may require supermajority approval on selected questions
Any of these rules may be set/ altered at any time by those with power to vote
Similar situation in other states - though different states create different presumptive rules, e.g. cumulative voting
Almost all shares have one vote; only shares possess votes
Preferred shares or bonds may acquire votes when the firm is in financial difficulty
Cumulative votes/ nonvoting stock/ stocks with seriously limited voting rights are rare in publicly-held corporations
Statutory limits on the ability of firms to create a voting structure
Investors may sell votes by selling the instrument to which the votes are attached
But cannot sell the votes independent of the instrument
Statute limit shareholders’ ability to grant...