INTENTIONAL TORTS
Intent
Applies to conduct, not the consequence
Vosburg v. Putney: D kicked P’s knee. Liable for all harm done because he intended to do a degree of harm.
Strict liability for all intent
Lack of knowledge does not mitigate
Intent only needs to be to do the action, not to do it to a specific P
Cannot use “I meant X, not Y” as a defense.
Policy: An accident is a side effect; direct result of something actor meant to do.
Substantial Certainty
If harm is substantially certain to result from D’s actions, the harm is treated as D’s intent even if it was not his goal.
Transferred Intent
If you intent to tort A but tort B instead, your tort on B is intentional.
Battery
Intentional harmful of offensive contact that does actual harm to P
Contact results, directly or indirectly, from D’s actions
Must go beyond incidental, harmless, and inoffensive touching
Vosburg: D’s kick was intentional and significant enough to constitute battery
Strict liability: D liable for all results of intended battery
Assault
Elements
Intentional act
Imminent threat to person
Tuberville v. Savage: “If it were not assis-time I would beat you” is not an assault because if it is assis-time, the threat is not imminent.
Timing of imminence is fuzzy; jury question.
Places P in reasonable apprehension of bodily harm
Not necessarily fear (whether the P is subjectively afraid is immaterial)
Emotional preparation to respond to imminent threat
P can be apprehensive and also reasonable believe that no real harm will come his way (bigger stick scenario)
Apprehension can be subjective; a person can be in apprehension of an unloaded gun they believe to be loaded (Allen v. Hannaford)
Does not require physical contact
Protects intangible interest in bodily integrity—emotions, security of the mind
Injury done is apprehension, an emotional harm
Trespass
Intent to enter real property
Dougherty v. Stepp: Intent element goes toward entering the land, not toward knowing it was private property.
Intent does not go toward it being someone else’s land; ignorance of ownership is no excuse. Just coming onto the land voluntarily is sufficient.
Strict liability for all damages caused by entry.
Property is subject to Eggshell Plaintiff
Intangible trespass: requirement is on P to show harm (not required for other types of trespass.)
E.g. harm from electric fields.
Policy: Trespass suits are often brought to get court ruling on where a party’s property line is.
Affirmative Defenses
Consent
Mohr v. Williams: D operated on P’s other ear and P claimed battery. Patient has autonomy unless there is an emergency or expressly implied consent.
Policy: Autonomy trumps best interests except in emergency cases
Good decision theory: Let the party (usually the person himself) in the best position make the decision.
General consent form: once you sign it, you turn over your autonomy to the doctor. Enables the doctor to make the best decisions for the patient without fear of malpractice.
Nonverbal Consent: Consent need not be spoken or written. Per custom, a person’s actions can be reasonably interpreted as giving consent.
Implicit consent: Sports
Combatants in sports consent to violence that occurs within normal boundaries of the sport, but not gratuitous violence. Hackbert v. Cincinnati Bengals
“Deliberate, willfull, or reckless disregard for safety”
Violent non fit injuria—the willing suffer no injury
Exception: Illegal Acts
Hudson: Cannot consent to an illegal prizefight; tort liability for battery done on the promoter.
Rule: No one can consent to participation in illegal activity
Consent is a common-law principle that can be superseded by statute
Cannot consent to unlawful activity
Torts adjust to fit criminal law
Safe Harbor
Sufficient but not necessary condition for preferential treatment
Localized rules establish consent for certain actions
E.g. the rules of football are a safe harbor for most batteries.
Necessity
When life or limb is threatened, normal rules of trespass do not apply.
Cuts back on rights of property owner.
Society values P’s life over D’s property rights
Threat must be serious, necessity action must be reasonable.
Self-help
OK to do things that would otherwise be torts if you interests have been invaded
Excessive self-help is a tort
Much harder to claim self-help when the harm is done to a person than to property.
Holdouts
Occurs when a bilateral monopoly exists
Deal in both parties’ interests is much more valuable to the party in need than the holder.
Damages
Owner can recover compensatory damages in necessity cases, but not punitive ones
Excessive self-help triggers punitive damages
Incentivizes P to only engage in self-help if there is true necessity—person in true need won’t consider costs.
Also a defense to CN. See Raimondo.
EMERGENCE OF NEGLIGENCE
Forms of Action
Trespass: Direct harm done
Scott v. Shepard
Lighted squib caused game of hot potato
Rule: Removing self from danger justifiable; blame on initial trespasser.
Guille v. Swan: Intent does not matter for trespass; strict liability for all injurt (balloon over NYC case).
Foundations for strict liability
Case (“trespass on the case”): Harm resulting from earlier actions
Foundation for negligence: creation of dangerous situation that ends up harming.
Problems
Wrong form of action resulted in dismissal
Interested parties could not testify
Introduction of Due Care
Brown v. Kendall (MA SJC, Shaw, landmark negligence case)
D accidently hit P with stick while trying to separate fighting dogs
Old trespass system: SL
Negligence: P had burden to show D was acting unreasonably
Old system required P to merely show causation
New rule: causation plus unreasonable want of due care
Brown v. Collins
D exercised reasonable care over horses, but they did damage anyway
P couldn’t show negligence and lost.
Duty to exercise due care extends to everyone
Old system: rule was SL, unless D was under specific duty, then negligence.
New system: negligence for all but certain exceptions
Modern Rule of Negligence: Action or failure to take action to avoid injury to another
Duty, Breach, Causation, Damages
Procedure: The jury, not the judge, determines what due care is and whether the parties took it
Pokora v. Wabash: Cardozo; negligence is a standard, not a rule. Contra Baltimore & OH v. Goodman; Holmes argued that judge should be able to instruct jury on what the reasonable person is.
Why Cardozo is right: Fact patterns are complicated and no singular judge rule can determine what a reasonable person would do in every possible situation. Better to make it a standard and let the jury apply that standard to the facts of the case.
Juries tend to favor D on liability, but award higher damages to P when D is found liable
Judges have seen so many things that they may not see the obvious answer in each case
Judge retains power to take case from jury when “no reasonable jury” situation arises
Juries have the sense of the common man and provide a check on the legal intelligentsia
Judge argument: all cases should be decided alike; fewer people deciding cases is better
Policy: Economics of Negligence
SL system was bankrupting industry
State could not afford to directly subsidize industry
Negligence lowered costs of doing business for factories, etc.
Only had to pay costs of precaution, not serve as an insurer for all employee accidents
Policy: Corrective Justice
With Strict Liability: Blameworthiness. Person at fault pays. Corrects all harms.
With Negligence: Golden rule. Liability only if person treated you at a standard of care lower than they would treat themselves.
Policy: Incentives
With Strict Liability: Precautions taken up to point of cost-efficiency. If you don’t take enough precaution, you pay.
With Negligence: Rewards people who take due care by releasing them from liability. Causes people’s conduct to reflect the effects of that conduct on others.
Injured P does not recover if D took due care.
Assuming others are taking due care, incentivizes P to avoid injury.
Policy: Paerto
Pareto improvement is a move that makes at least one person better w/o making anyone worse
Pareto optimality is when all possible Pareto improvements have been made
Policy: Kaldor-Hicks Efficiency
Conduct is negligent if disadvantages outweigh advantages
Advantage can be saving money by not taking precaution against unlikely events.
Not the same as a Pareto improvement: A person can be made worse off, but so long as the person benefitting can compensate the person being harmed, it works.
This is how the legal system works. Take precautions that are justified and be prepared to pay the other person for what you don’t precaution for.
You can be forced by the legal system to make a K-H improvement.
This encourages internalization of risk. Look at what is cost-justified to do.
Policy changes should be made if they benefit X more than they harm Y
Policy: Activity Level
Strict Liability: The law of odds says that even if taking due care, you will eventually be in an accident if you do something often enough, and will have to pay. Disincentivizes activities (driving)
Thus we only impose it for activities we want to limit the use of (ultrahazardous)
Negligence: Doesn’t discourage activities. Negligence only cares about how you drive, SL cares about how much you drive.
THE REASONABLE PERSON STANDARD
Objective Standard of Care